Tiger.gatech.edu
The outsourcing of R&D through acquisitions in the
pharmaceutical industry†
Matthew J. Higgins
Department of Finance
J. Mack Robinson College of Business
Georgia State University
Atlanta, GA 30302-3991
[email protected]
Daniel Rodriguez
Department of Organization & Management
Goizueta Business School, Emory University
Atlanta, GA 30322-2710
27 February 2005
We examine the performance of 160 pharmaceutical acquisitions from 1994-2001 and find evidence that on average acquirers realize significant positive returns. These returns are positively correlated with prior acquirer access to information about the research and development activities at target firms and a superior negotiating position. A unique
Desperation Index is employed in order to determine the current status of a firm's internal productivity. We find that firms experiencing declines in internal productivity or which are more desperate are more likely to engage in an outsourcing type acquisition in an effort to replenish their research pipelines. Key words: acquisitions; asymmetric information; winner's curse; pharmaceutical industry JEL: G34, D82
† We received helpful comments and suggestions from Tamer Abdelgawad, George Benston, Gavin Drummond, Michael Hammock, Christina Kelton, Alan Petersen, Frank Rothaermel, Paula Stephan, Mike Stonebrook, Tom Thomas, Jerry Thursby, Marie Thursby, Leslie Harris-Vincent as well as seminar participants at Emory University, Georgia Institute of Technology, University of Georgia and the 2002 and 2003 Southern Economic Association meetings. We also thank the comments from an anonymous referee. The first author acknowledges financial assistance from a National Science Foundation IGERT Fellowship (Grant # 0221600). The second author acknowledges funding from a Goizueta Business School Research Fellowship. All remaining errors and omissions are our own. Corresponding author: Matthew J. Higgins, Department of Finance, J. Mack Robinson College of Business, P.O. Box 3991, Atlanta, GA 30302-3991, phone: 404.651.2671,
[email protected] 2005 by Matthew J. Higgins and Daniel Rodriguez. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including notice, is given to the source.
1.0
Researchers have documented that acquirers generally realize negative returns from
acquisitions or, at best, break even. We document findings indicating how acquirers have been
able to avoid the winner's curse by obtaining information about the true underlying value of the
target firm prior to acquisition. This information advantage for acquirers enables them to avoid
the three major pitfalls that typically characterize unsuccessful acquisitions: 1) overbidding for
the target firm, 2) selecting an incorrect target firm, and 3) failing at the post-acquisition
integration process.
Instead of investigating a heterogeneous sample of acquisitions, we focus on research and
development-directed acquisitions in the biopharmaceutical industry. This focused examination
has two main advantages. First, it allows us to use the extensive publicly available data for both
the acquiring and target firms involved in new drug research that are related to informational
asymmetries. Secondly, it provides measures of acquirer firm performance subsequent to an
acquisition directly related to R&D productivity, specifically product pipeline improvements.
We make four contributions to the literature. First, we find evidence consistent with the
proposition that deteriorating R&D productivity may be the motivation underlying the
acquisition of research-intensive biotech firms. An integrated data sample of four
complementary data sources allows us to test
why and
which firms engage in outsourcing R&D-
type acquisitions. Relatively few studies focus on the motivation behind a firm's acquisition
decision.1 In this paper, we find that firms that are experiencing the greatest deterioration in their
R&D productivity are most likely to undertake the acquisition of a research-intensive firm.
Second, we find evidence consistent with the proposition that biopharmaceutical firms
can successfully outsource R&D through acquisitions. These acquisitions appear to effectively
supplement a firm's internal R&D efforts and R&D-focused alliances. Overall, we find positive
announcement period cumulative abnormal returns for our acquiring companies of positive 3.91
percent.2 This figure is greater than previous results reported in the existing literature.3,4 In
1 Andrade, Mitchell & Stafford (2001) point out that "…if mergers could be sorted by their true underlying motivations, it may be those which are undertaken for good reasons do benefit acquirers, but in the average statistics, they are canceled out by those with bad reasons."
2 Significant at the 1% level.
3 Andrade, Mitchell & Stafford (2001) report average announcement period abnormal returns of –0.70 percent for acquiring firms across 3,688 different acquisitions from 1973–1998. These abnormal returns fell to -1.00 percent when focused on 1,864 deals from 1990-1998.
addition to the significant financial gains to our sample acquirers, we find real measures of
success. For example, 71 percent of acquirers in our sample either maintain or improve their
product pipelines or portfolios post-acquisition.
Third, we find that access to information by the acquirer during the pre-acquisition period
leads to greater acquirer success. Most acquisition research concludes that acquiring companies
pay too much for a target and little or no value is created for their shareholders when a
significant portion of the target firm's value consists of intangible assets.5 One reason for such
overpayment is the difficulty in valuing intangible assets. To overcome these valuation
difficulties, we hypothesize that an acquirer can obtain significant additional information through
pre-acquisition alliances with the target firm or alliances with firms conducting research that is
similar to that of the potential target firm. The acquirer can also obtain additional insights into
the underlying value of the target by drawing upon its own internal research experience. We find
that pre-acquisition information-gathering activities are positively and significantly correlated
with acquirer success.
Fourth, according to Samuelson and Bazerman (1985) acquirers engaged in bilateral
negotiations with a target firm that may have superior information regarding the true value of its
assets tend to succumb to the winner's curse. We find, though, that acquirers can mitigate
overbidding by bidding from an advantageous negotiating position. Our results indicate that
acquirer gains are positively correlated with the pre-acquisition strength of the acquirer's new
product pipeline and exclusive products portfolio.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: section 2 briefly discusses
productivity trends in the pharmaceutical industry; section 3 provides a brief discussion of the
relevant literature; section 4 discusses the empirical methodology and data used in our analysis;
section 5 presents and discusses our empirical finding; and we conclude in section 6 by
summarizing the analysis and discussing the implications of our results.
2.0
Productivity Trends in the Pharmaceutical Industry
4 Bruner (2002) provides a comprehensive review of the current literature on M&As and summarizes the results for acquirer shareholders in Table III, which range from –14.2 percent to +3.24 percent for non-tender offer transactions.
5 See Rodriguez and Higgins (2003) for a notable exception among software acquisitions.
Productivity in the pharmaceutical industry -- as reflected by the overall industry
exclusivity and patent horizon -- has been declining in the late 1990s, because more drugs are
coming off exclusivity protection than are being replaced by new Food & Drug Administration
(FDA) approved products.6 Exclusivity refers to exclusive regulatory marketing rights granted
by the FDA under 21 C.F.R. 314.108, which prevents generic products from entering the market.
The pharmaceutical industry had a combined total of approximately 1,146 years of
aggregate exclusivity protection in 1998. The exclusivity horizon had fallen to just over 800
years by 2001 and the rate of decline has been fairly rapid. Figure 1 plots the total number of
exclusive years for each product currently approved by the FDA7. The aging of the overall
industry product profile is one reason for this rapid decline. In addition, new products take an
average of 10-15 years to develop from initial discovery to final FDA approval. (DiMasi, 2001)
From 1988-2001, the average time the FDA took to approve a new drug was approximately 20
months. (FTC, 2002) Over the same time period, the cost of developing a new drug product has
increased from $231 million in 1987 to $802 million in 2000. (DiMasi, 2001) Domestic research
and development expenditures have followed the same trend. In 1990, R&D expenditures for
U.S. pharmaceutical companies totaled $6.8 billion and have grown to over $21.3 billion in
2000. However, as a percentage of sales, R&D expenditures have remained fairly stable at
around 17 percent from 1990 to 2001, peaking at 20.4 percent of sales in 1997. (PhRMA, 2002)
In response to this decline in R&D productivity, pharmaceutical firms have pursued
several options: (1) enhance their internal R&D efforts through the acquisition of smaller
pharmaceutical and/or biotech companies; (2) engage in large horizontal mergers to achieve
greater economies of scale and scope in their research programs; (3) acquire existing mature
products through licensing agreements; (4) increase organic internal R&D efforts independently;
(5) increase alliance activity; or (6) change their fundamental business model. These options are
by no means mutually exclusive; in reality, companies usually engage in a number of these
activities at varying levels. In this paper we explore the first response – the impact that the
outsourcing of R&D through acquisition has had on individual firm R&D productivity.
6 One explanation put forth by industry representatives for this decline is that the "easy" drugs have already been developed – the drugs currently under development are much more sophisticated and target more difficult diseases. A second explanation, described in the Wall Street Journal ("Drug Industry's Big Push Into Technology Falls Short", February 24, 2004), suggests that the heavy reliance on combinatorial chemistry and high-throughput screening did not produce the "hits" that were initially hoped for when this technology was adopted in the 1990s.
7 This information is publicly available in the FDA's Orange Book.
3.0
Acquisitions and the outsourcing of R&D
3.1 Relevant research on merger and acquisitions
A significant quantity of research has been dedicated to understanding for whom and how
value is created through acquisitions. Many theories have emerged, for example, the monopoly
theory of mergers (Mueller, 1985; Eckbo, 1992; and Ravenscraft and Scherer, 1987); the
synergies approach (Bradley
et al, 1989); economies of scale (Ravenscraft and Scherer, 1989;
Houston
et al, 2001); to gain market power (Anand and Singh, 1997; Baker and Bresnehan,
1985; Barton and Sherman, 1984); redeployment of assets (Capron, 1999); and, diversification.
(Berger and Ofek, 1995)
The conclusion one draws from the bulk of the research focusing on whether value is
"created" or "destroyed" is that the return to acquiring firm shareholders, on average, is
essentially zero.8 The majority of the value flows to the target firm shareholders.9 (Jensen and
Ruback, 1983; Brickley and Netter, 1988; Bruner, 2002) Relatively few studies have been able
to demonstrate meaningful value gains on behalf of acquiring firms in non-tender offer
acquisitions. Andrade
et al (2001) suggests that the underlying strategic motivation for a
particular transaction may provide a fruitful avenue for identifying how value is created through
acquisitions for acquirer shareholders. Since companies merge for multiple reasons, it may be
the case that companies engaging in mergers for "bad" reasons are negating the gains to
companies engaging in mergers for "good" reasons. Mitchell & Lehn (1990) have shown
empirically that there are both good and bad transactions from the viewpoint of the acquiring
companies' shareholders. Andrade, Mitchell & Stafford (2001) offer five motivations for
acquisition: (1) efficiency-related reasons that involve economies of scale or other synergies; (2)
creation of market power; (3) market discipline; (4) self-serving attempts by acquirer
management to over-expand; and (5) diversification. Each of these strategic motivations,
however, has its own distinct set of problems and concerns. It may be the case then, that by
grouping all transactions together we are unable to clearly look at them in any meaningful
manner. By classifying acquisitions into appropriate categories of transactions, we may be able
8 See Kohlers and Kohlers (2001); Ecko and Thorburn (2000); Lyroudi, Lazardis and Subeniotis (1999); Schwert (1996); and Andrade, Mitchell and Stafford (2001)
to determine which strategic motivation for mergers is flawed, and thereby predisposed to
destroy shareholder value. Researchers can then begin to focus on these different underlying
motivations and determine why a particular strategy has been successful or unsuccessful.
3.2
Outsourcing of research and development
Mergers and acquisitions as a method for outsourcing research and development is one of
the justifications for acquisition activity observed during the latter 1990s. Pharmaceutical
companies, in particular, have begun to supplement internal R&D efforts through acquisition.
Chesbrough (2003) discusses the importance of a company's need to address their research gaps
in a timely manner. One of the methods he suggests to fill these research gaps is through the
acquisition of external technologies. In addition, James (2002) discusses the role mergers and
acquisitions can play in enhancing a firm's internal capability. For example, in discussing their
December 2002 acquisition of Triangle Pharmaceuticals, a Gilead Sciences' spokeswoman said,
"We had a need to build our pipeline. This acquisition brings to Gilead not only a late-stage
product that could launch next year, but a pipeline of other drugs in development."10 Merck
provides another interesting example of this trend. In March 2002 Merck's CEO lauded the
company's pipeline of products which numbered 11 potential treatments that were slated to
launch over the next few years. However, as of November 2003, only two of the products have
launched. A third product was in the process of being filed. Two product's filings have been
delayed until 2006 and six products have either been canceled or delayed indefinitely.11 These
cancellations and failures have caused Merck's pipeline to deteriorate significantly.
Subsequently, in February 2004, Merck acquired Aton Pharmaceuticals Inc., a privately held
biotechnology company. In describing the acquisition Merck said "The acquisition…will
enhance its [Merck] internal research efforts to develop potential new medicines for the
treatment of cancer…"12
In addition to having an understanding of what they are purchasing, acquiring companies
must also have the absorptive capacity to integrate the acquired research into their own R&D
9 See Houston, James, and Ryngaert (2001); DeLong (2001); Eckbo and Thorburn (2000); and Bruner (2001)
10 Smartmoney.com, "If you can't beat em, buy em", December 4, 2002.
11 Wall Street Journal, November 28, 2003.
12 Wall Street Journal, "Merck to Buy Aton Pharmaceuticals", February 23, 2004.
program. Cohen and Levinthal (1989) postulate that a firm's absorptive capacity will be based
on their own internal research and development efforts. As a result, regardless of the external
R&D activities that an acquiring company may engage in, it will still be important for the firm to
continue to pursue a comprehensive internal research program. Chesbrough (2003)
One challenge that acquirers face in these types of acquisitions is holding on to essential
target firm employees who may represent a significant portion of firm value at the target. In
contrast to the primary findings in the extant literature -- for example, Andrade (2001) and Myers
and Majluf (1984) -- equity deals may be preferable to cash deals. Equity deals may be more
effective in aligning the interests of employees at the target firm with those at the acquiring firm.
This type of moral hazard problem is discussed by Jensen and Thursby (2001) within the context
of university licensing agreements. They find that the use of equity in order to induce scientists
to continue to remain committed to a project is an effective measure for reducing the moral
hazard problem. Additionally, the willingness of the target firm in these transactions to accept
equity payment also serves as a signal to the market regarding their on-going commitment to
their research post-acquisition.
3.3
Information gathering and the winner's curse
Asymmetric information in acquisitions is potentially a significant problem. For our
specific example of acquisitions, this problem is compounded given the knowledge-intensive
nature of the industry. Knowledge-based assets, in general, are more difficult to assess than
tangible ones. One of the concerns for an acquiring company is their ability to accurately value
the target firm. Firms that attempt to make acquisitions outside of their core competencies may
have difficulty adding value to the firm. (Williamson, 1975) Given this potential difficulty, it
makes sense for knowledge-intensive firms to pursue targets with similar competencies.13
Chatterjee and Wernerfelt (1991) and Samuelson and Bazerman (1985) suggest that when
acquiring firms engage in negotiations with target firms that have superior information regarding
the true value of its assets, the acquiring firm will tend to succumb to the winner's curse and
overpay for the target. The winner's curse arises due to the uncertainty over the value of the
target firm's assets.
We propose that firms pursuing knowledge-intensive acquisitions must engage in
some
pre-acquisition information gathering, besides normal corporate due diligence, in order to
diminish the amount of asymmetric information between the acquirer and the target firms. The
pre-acquisition information activities that we consider include: alliances prior to an acquisition
with the target firm, alliances with other firms within the same therapeutic category as the
acquisition, and internal research and prior sales experience within the same therapeutic category
as the target firm. These activities function as a feedback mechanism which allows acquiring
companies to generate information on a potential target. The pharmaceutical acquirers in our
sample have been and continue to be heavily focused upon research and development; we can
presume they are experts in evaluating the future profitability of basic research. As such, if an
acquiring firm is engaged in similar research as a target firm, it should be able to place a more
accurate value on the target research, potentially avoiding the typical overpayment associated
with the winner's curse. Additionally, prior contact with the target firm through alliances gives
the two firms an opportunity to "learn" about each other's research and also meet and work with
key scientists and management.14 In the current analysis, each acquiring firm has, on average,
four prior alliances with the target firm
prior to the acquisition. This contact should provide the
acquiring firm with sufficient information regarding the human capital of the target firm.
Combined, these pre-acquisition activities should provide enough information to the acquirer so
that it "knows what it is buying." This type of organizational learning perspective is broadly
similar to that suggested by Hayward (2002).
In addition to providing information, Rothaermel (2001) finds that alliances with
providers of new technologies are positively correlated with new product development for the
incumbent firm and, in turn, new product development is positively associated with firm
performance. This finding is supported elsewhere in the literature, for example, Shan et al
(1994) and Deeds and Hill (1997).
Acquirers in the pharmaceutical industry are able to negotiate more effectively with the
target firm when the exclusivity and patent horizon of their own product portfolios and their
product pipelines are strong. We argue they undertake acquisitions to supplement their slowing
13 In fact, 82 percent of the acquisitions in the current project are ones that involve firms with complementary research.
14 Anand and Khanna (2000) show that firms can
learn to create value as their alliance experience accumulates over time.
R&D productivity as evidenced by an increase in their
Desperation Index (our unique
quantitative measure of firm level desperation), which will be discussed more fully below. Firms
are able to capture value from their acquisition activities by improving their stock of knowledge
or information about the target prior to the time of the acquisition. As such, we make the
following predictions: (1) the probability that a given firm undertakes a R&D acquisition will be
positively related its level of desperation just prior to an acquisition; (2) given that a firm makes
an acquisition, the cumulative abnormal return,
CAR, realized from the acquisition will be positively related to the stock of information accumulated by the acquirer in the period prior to
an acquisition; (3) the
CAR realized from an acquisition will be negatively related to the acquirer's level of desperation; (4) post-acquisition improvements in R&D productivity or
pipeline health of an acquirer will be positively related to acquirer's pre-acquisition information
gathering activities; and, (5) post-acquisition improvements in pipeline health of an acquirer will
be positively related to the acquirer's level of desperation prior to an acquisition.
4.0 Empirical Methodology and Data Sample
4.1 Empirical
We use event study methodology to compute the cumulative abnormal returns around the
time of the acquisition announcement. Acquisition dates for the sample were gathered from
Securities Data Corporation (SDC) and verified using publicly available media reports from
The
Wall Street Journal and other business publications. We ran the event study utilizing an event
window of three days. The three day window includes the day of the announcement as well as
the day before and after. As a robustness check, we re-ran the event study utilizing a five day
window. The five day window includes the three days prior to an acquisition announcement, the
day of the announcement as well as the day after. Finally, we checked for confounding events
for each transaction with
The Wall Street Journal.15
15 Major corporate events including: litigation, naming of new CEO or senior management, new product announcements, earnings and dividend announcements, major news relating to success or failure of a drug in clinical trials, rulings by the FDA and other mergers, joint venture or alliance announcements were considered confounding events. Firms for which confounding events are identified were excluded from our sample.
One of the challenges in analyzing mergers and acquisitions is to find appropriate
measures of transactions success, in addition to the widely accepted cumulative abnormal
returns. Healey, Palepu, and Ruback (1992) use post-acquisition accounting data to test directly
for changes in operating performance that result from mergers. This approach would not be
appropriate for the current analysis, because it overlooks the health of the acquiring company's
product pipeline, which represents potential future significant cash flows that are not recorded in
available accounting data. We examine two measures of acquisition success in addition to
cumulative abnormal returns. First, we look at the post-acquisition change in the product
pipeline for the year following the acquisition. We quantitatively measure each company's
pipeline using a unique "
Score" value, which will be discussed below. If pipeline products were
included in the acquisition, the company's post acquisition product pipeline
Score value should
increase. This would be one indication that the company was successful in making
improvements to its product pipeline as a result of R&D acquisitions. Second, we look at post-
acquisition changes in revenues in the year following the acquisition. This measure is less
precise for two reasons. First, since many of the acquisitions are smaller in size, even if a
company acquired a mature product with existing sales, those added sales may not be enough to
counteract the firm's existing loss in sales due to current products coming off patent. Second,
pipeline products that are acquired by a firm will most likely not have sales in the following year,
unless the product has already been submitted for FDA approval.16 To test our primary
predictions, we employ regression analysis controlling for firm characteristics and transaction
characteristics expected to affect the value creation resulting from acquisitions in our sample
using our standard measure of acquirer success,
CARs, and two industry-specific measures of
success, improved product pipeline and new drug product sales.
4.2 Acquisition
We obtained acquisitions data from Thomson Financial's Securities Data Corporation
(SDC) database for the years 1994-2001. We identified transactions representative of the new
16 The inability to extend this beyond one year post-acquisition is a function of our data range. Since our data ends in 2001, we are limited to the number of years we can extend the analysis post-acquisition without losing data points. Our current research project is looking at the status of the acquired pipeline products in the post-acquisition period.
product-focused biotechnology industry acquisitions by the primary acquirer SIC code and by
SDC's "high-tech" search variable. SIC codes 2833-2836 cover the pharmaceutical industry.
The "high-tech" industry classification by SDC identified firms within the biotechnology
industry, but with SIC codes other than 2833-2836. This search method also identified high-tech
companies in different sectors. As a result, we filtered the data set using SDC's "business
description" and "sector" variables. Acquisitions that clearly were outside of the
biopharmaceutical sector were deleted from the data set. Unrelated acquisitions were considered
to be those that included over-the-counter or generic drugs, consumer products, medical devices
and products, and manufacturing facilities. In addition to filtering the sample to verify the
relevance of the acquisition in question, we collected additional information from news stories
from Factiva. First, we verified the value and method of payment of the acquisition, when
disclosed. Second, we noted the company's stated reason for entering into the acquisition.
Third, the relatedness of the firms was coded. Firms were coded as "related" if the target
company's research or products were within the same therapeutic category as the acquiring
company.17 The purpose of this classification is determine whether firms were making
acquisitions within their current competency or whether they were venturing to build a new
competency. This filtering process left approximately 180 transactions spanning 15 countries,
with the majority of the acquirers and targets, 76 percent and 80 percent, respectively, being
based in the United States. We obtained domestic stock market returns data from CRSP and
international returns data from Data Stream. Twenty transactions were dropped from the final
sample due to inadequate data; in some of these cases, both parties were private entities and
information about the transaction was severely limited or not available.
4.3
Exclusivity horizon and patent profiles
4.3.1 Implications of Hatch-Waxman
17 Firms were categorized into broad therapeutic categories based upon the Uniform Standard of Classification. For coding purposes we looked at several sources for therapeutic information about firms. For example, we utilized the therapeutic coding available from our proprietary sales data set, the NDA pipeline, company websites and the news releases about the acquisition itself.
Two types of patent protection exist for pharmaceutical companies. The first are
traditional patents granted and processed by the United States Patent and Trademark Office
(USPTO). The Uruguay Round Agreements Act of 1994 extended patent lengths from 17 years
from the date the patent was granted to 20 years from the date the application is filed.
Traditional patents can be filed anywhere along the development lifeline of a drug and they can
encompass a wide range of claims. In fact, most approved pharmaceutical products have several
patents attached to them. For example, the new Eli Lilly drug
Cialis™ which was approved on
November 21, 2003, has two separate patents associated with their new drug application
The second type of protection is regulatory in nature and granted by the FDA upon actual
approval of a new chemical entity (NCE). This type of protection is termed
exclusivity and may
run concurrent with traditional patent protection. For a NCE, exclusivity is granted for a period
of five years from the date of FDA approval.19 Exclusivity came about as an important provision
in the Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Act of 1984 – more commonly referred to as the
Hatch-Waxman Act. The purpose of exclusivity was to provide pharmaceutical companies five
years of marketing protection during which other manufacturers were prohibited from filing an
application to sell a generic product. Exclusivity does not, however, prevent other manufacturers
from seeking approval for a drug that uses the same therapeutic mechanism as an already
approved drug. These products are often referred to as "me-too" drugs and are required to
undergo the same rigorous clinical testing in order to garner FDA approval.20 For example, the
erectile dysfunction drugs
Cialis™ and
Levitra™ -- direct competitors of the already marketed
drug
Viagra™ -- were approved on November 2, 2003 and August 19, 2003 respectively. The
exclusivity provision was designed to help firms that had no patent protection, or had very little
time left under patent by the time a NCE was finally approved by the FDA.
18 Two patents -- numbers 5859006 and 6140329 expiring on January 12, 2016 and July 11, 2016, respectively – were attached to the NDA in the FDA Orange Book.
19 Orphan (for rare diseases and disorders) and pediatric drugs are granted longer exclusivity periods due to their more limited use. For example, orphan drugs are granted 7 years of exclusivity protection.
20 This is in contrast to generic drugs which, according to the Hatch-Waxman Act, only need to demonstrate "bio-equivalence" to an already approved brand name drugs in order to get FDA approval. Bioequivalence means that the active ingredient in the generic drug is absorbed at the same rate as the brand name drug. The test required to demonstrate bioequivalence are much less costly than those undertaken by brand name drugs. This provision in Hatch-Waxman has allowed generics to enter the market quickly and at much lower cost. For example, prior to Hatch-Waxman in 1983, only 35 percent of top-selling drugs with expired patents faced generic competition. By 1998, that number was close to 100 percent. (CBO, 1998)
Our goal is to construct an exclusivity and patent profile for each pharmaceutical
company with an approved product. The purpose of such an exercise is to provide a measure of
the health of an individual company's patented product profile. The FDA Orange Book indicates
when a NCE is formally approved by the FDA. Along with this approval is the granting of
exclusivity by the FDA. According to 21 C.F.R. § 314.53, upon submission of a new drug
application (NDA) for consideration by the FDA, pharmaceutical firms are required to submit
relevant and supporting patent information. For patents issued after the approval of an NDA,
firms are required to submit relevant patent information within 30 days.
Unfortunately, several issues arise when trying to use the FDA Orange Book to construct
our exclusivity and patent profiles which must be taken into consideration. First, exclusivity and
patent lengths are not static. That is to say there are ways in which companies are allowed to
extend the length of both their exclusivity and patent protection. The allowances for both of
these extensions flow from the Hatch-Waxman Act. In terms of patent protection, companies
that have received approval for a NCE by the FDA can apply to have half the time the drug spent
in clinical trials (approximately four to eight years) plus all of the time spent having the FDA
review (usually two years) its new drug application added onto its patent length. There are three
limitations. First, the extension cannot be longer than five years. Second, the total granted
patent length of a drug cannot exceed 14 years after the drug has been approved and, third,
companies must apply for this extension within 60 days of FDA approval. (CBO, 1998)
Additionally, only one patent is eligible for the Hatch-Waxman extension. As a result, most
firms will choose to extend the patent that covers the drug's chemical compound or in the
alternative, the patent that covers the use of the drug. (CBO, 1998)
The Hatch-Waxman Act also provides for extensions to exclusivity protection. The act
allows for the granting of three additional years of exclusivity for a supplemental NDA if the
application required additional clinical testing. Manufacturers will often use this provision in
order to obtain approval for new dosages of previously approved products. Schering used these
provisions effectively in the follow-up introductions of
Claritin-D™ and
Claritin-D 24 Hour™ to
there hit allergy medicine
Claritin™, which was originally approved on April 4, 1993. The logic
behind this provision is to provide an incentive for manufacturers to continually improve brand-
name products. (CBO, 1998)
When a generic manufacturer makes an application (called an Abbreviated New Drug
Approval or ANDA) to the FDA the ANDA must contain a certification regarding each of the
patents listed in the Orange Book. There are four possible certifications that can be made.21 Of
relevance to the current discussion as it relates to the extension of exclusivity are "Paragraph IV
Certifications". With this certification a generic manufacturer is challenging that a listed patent
is either invalid or will not be infringed upon by the generic drug. The manufacturer making this
claim must provide the patent holder with their factual and legal basis for their filing. The patent
holder then has 45 days in which to file an infringement suit. By filing an infringement suit, the
FDA sets aside the approval process for the ANDA until the earliest of: (1) the date the NDA
patent being challenged expires, (2) there is a court ruling invalidating the patent, (3) a court
ruling of non-infringement, or (4) 30 months after the patent holder was originally notified of the
ANDA Paragraph IV certification. The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) estimates that
Paragraph IV challenges, on average, take approximately 25 months to adjudicate. (FTC, 2002)
In effect, brand-name manufacturers are able to tack on another two and one-half years of
additional exclusivity protection thereby increasing their effective exclusivity period to seven
and one-half years.22
Unfortunately, these provisions to extend exclusivity and patent protection have been
increasingly used in an effort to stave off generic competition by the brand-name
manufacturers.23 Bulow (2003) provides a more complete discussion of the type of "gaming"
that has taken place. As a result, the FDA Orange Book, which provides an accurate picture of
new drug approvals, may be missing relevant patent data. We next discuss the construction of
our variables and the potential biases, we feel, that may be introduced as a result of the above
4.3.2 Exclusivity & Patent Profiles
21 See Bulow (2003) for a description of the four certifications.
22 In their report, the FTC noted that the prevalence of infringement suits increased after 1998. (FTC, 2002)
23 This process appears to have been abused in the past. For example, Bristol Meyers Squibb (BMS) announced that they would pay a total of $670 million to settle anti-trust suits relating to
Buspar and
Taxol. One of the allegations made was that the improperly listed a patent in the Orange Book extending their exclusivity. (
In re Busprinoe Patent Litigation, MDL No. 1410 (S.D.N.Y.))
Three separate data sources are utilized in generating our firm and industry exclusivity
and patent profiles. Since there is the possibility of underreporting in the FDA Orange book, two
other sources, Thomson Derwent and NERAC, are used in an attempt to identify additional
patents that could be used by the firm in order to extend protections. The goal in utilizing these
added data sets is to attempt to capture additional, unreported patents that are relevant to a
particular approved product. The net result of using this combination of data is that we create a
bound for each of our profile measures. A lower bound is created by the use of the FDA Orange
Book since there is potential underreporting of patents. An upper bound is created by the
combination of Derwent and NERAC. We make the claim that an upper bound is generated
since theses datasets attempt to identify additional patents tied to a particular approved product
that are not identified in the FDA Orange book. Since this process of attaching additional
patents to a particular approved product is rather subjective it is
possible that some of the patents
identified and attached to a product
may not be useable by the firm in efforts to increase patent
protection or stave off generic competition.24
In addition to these raw patent and exclusivity profiles a third measure is created. This
measure is a sales-weighted exclusivity horizon. Since not all approved products are worth the
same in terms of revenues, it makes sense that not all patents are worth the same. By sales-
weighting our exclusivity measure we are able to discern the status of the most important patents
to the firm, in terms of revenues. We constructed this by obtaining proprietary sales data from
IMS Health for every patented drug in the FDA's Orange Book files from 1994-2001.25 We
combined the two data sets for each product to obtain a weighted product exclusivity horizon.
Each product was weighted according to the proportion of sales represented by the average
product life cycle of all drugs in the FDA Orange Book. The average product life cycle was
determined as the proportion of sales in each year of exclusivity through three years following
loss of exclusivity protection. Over the entire Orange Book file, 74.19 percent of sales occurred
during the five-year exclusivity protection period, while an additional 15 percent of sales were
realized in the three years following the loss of exclusivity. We chose this weighting technique
in an effort to reflect each product's position correctly within its individual product sales life
24 We thank a patent attorney specializing in biopharmaceutical patents, who requested to remain anonymous, for spending countless hours answering questions relating to these issues.
25 150 patented products identified in the Orange Book files did not have sales data identified in IMS Health's data set; this left 398 patented products with sales data.
cycle. This life-cycle measure also provides some empirical insight into the previous discussion
relating to potential "gaming" in the FDA Orange Book. Since 74.19 percent of sales across the
FDA Orange book are occurring within a drug's first five years of sales, this suggests that the
impact of "gaming" may not yet be that significant. On average, the vast majority of
pharmaceutical sales for a product are still occurring within their first five years of approval.
The exclusivity horizon for the sector, regardless of the measure used, indicates that the
cumulative horizon is declining. Figure 1 plots the cumulative number of years of exclusive
marketing rights remaining for all patented products for the years 1991-2002. The range was
extended beyond our sample length of 1994-2001 to demonstrate the longer run trend. Two
potential extensions of the number of exclusive years were discussed; this graph takes into
consideration one of those concerns. When companies apply for a supplemental NDA as a result
of a new dosage or use, those products are listed separately and as a result, are captured in this
measure.26 It is possible that
some firms for
some products may have a longer exclusivity
The cumulative patent profile for the sector also follows a similar pattern as the
exclusivity profile. The cumulative exclusivity horizon peaked in 1998, while the overall patent
profile peaked in 1999. There are two possible reasons the cumulative years for the patent profile
exceed the cumulative years in the exclusivity profile. First, exclusivity protection is only
granted to products that have been approved by the FDA. There are many projects in earlier
stage testing that have received regular patent protection, but are ineligible for exclusivity
protection. Second, an approved product is granted exclusivity only once, while at the same time
an approved product may have a series of patents tied to it that extend back to the early-stage
discovery process. For example, product "X" will be given five years of exclusivity protection
(excluding any possible extensions), but may have several patents associated with it with varying
lengths of protected time remaining.
4.3
New Drug Approval (NDA) pipeline
26 These products were also listed separately in our proprietary sales data.
In an effort to determine what products are in development for acquirer firms, we use the
NDA Pipeline files from 1994-2001. These files contain information relating to the various
stages of product development. For purposes of this study we focus on the following phases:
pre-clinical, Phase I, Phase II, Phase III and FDA filed. Phase I involves safety testing, Phase II
focuses on small-scale human efficacy trials and Phase III focuses on large-scale human efficacy
trials. We group all pre-Phase I research into the "pre-clinical" category. We were also able to
identify the broad therapeutic categories where this research is focused.27 For example, over the
entire time period, 18.56 percent of all treatments in various stages of development are related in
some way to oncology. While the sheer numbers of potential treatments has grown, the number
of treatments actually being taken to the last stage – filing with the FDA – has remained
relatively constant. The ratio of treatments that make it to FDA filing over the number of
treatments in Phase III has declined from 29 percent to 17 percent throughout the 1990s.
Clinical probabilities are subsequently assigned to each of the various phases of research.
These assigned clinical probabilities, based on existing research, reflect the chance a potential
treatment has of receiving FDA approval (Krieger and Ruback, 2001). We subsequently employ
these values to construct a weighted value of each company's pipeline products, which we refer
to as the
Score. A relatively high
Score indicates a healthy product pipeline, in that higher
Score
values are reflective of a greater number of later stage products in the pipeline. For example, a
firm with a small number of Phase II or Phase III products would have a higher
Score value that
a firm with a large number of pre-clinical or Phase I products. The more important element,
however, is not necessarily the level of the
Score in any given year, but rather the trend of the
Score in the years prior to and after an acquisition. A declining
Score in the years prior to an
acquisition would be indicative of a company whose product pipeline was deteriorating.
The overall industry
Score value shows a marked increase in the mid-1990s and is
reflective of an underlying increase in the number of products in the NDA pipeline. Figure 2
plots the cumulative number of products in their various stages of pipeline research over our
sample period. The number of early-stage pipeline products dramatically increased in the late
1990s as did, to a lesser extent, the number of late-stage products. Actual FDA approvals
throughout this time period, however, have remained fairly constant at around 50. Reflecting
27 According to the Uniform Standard of Classification.
back to Figure 1, the increase in pipeline products has yet to produce sufficient numbers of new
products to stem the decline in industry-wide firm exclusivity horizons.
In the analysis that follows we utilize the raw
Score values in the two years prior to the
acquisition, the year of the acquisition and the year following an acquisition. In addition, two
changes in
Score value are considered. First, we look at the change in the
Score value between
the year of the acquisition and the year prior. Second, we look at the change between the year
after the acquisition and year of the acquisition. By using these different combinations we can
look at both levels and changes in the
Score.
4.4
For our analysis we use a proprietary set of alliance data provided by Recombinant
Capital. This data identifies alliances in the biopharmaceutical industry from 1973 through
2003. It also provides a general description of the nature of these alliances. This information
provides two important acquirer firm attributes for our present analysis: (1) whether the
acquiring company had any alliances with the target company prior to the acquisition; and, (2)
what type of alliances these were for example, licensing, research, development, co-
development, co-marketing, distribution, or manufacturing. We are also able to determine
whether an alliance was for an early or late stage product. In addition to alliances between our
acquirer and target, we also specify two other categories of alliances. The first category is
whether or not the acquiring company engaged in
any alliances prior to the acquisition with other
firms other than the target. The second category of alliances is whether the acquiring company
engaged in any other alliances within the same therapeutic category as the target, but with a firm
other than the target. We believe prior alliance activity with the target provides the most specific
opportunity for an acquiring company to "learn" about the target firm. In fact, 67 percent of the
sample acquirers engaged in, on average, four alliances with the target prior to the acquisition. 28
4.5
Desperation Index
28 Target firms, on average, had six alliances with firms
other than the acquiring firm prior to the acquisition.
Through the combination of these data we construct a categorical
Desperation Index. We
place each firm in the sample into one of four categories of desperation based upon whether or
not the change in their
Score value and sales-weighted exclusivity horizon is increasing or
decreasing in the year immediately prior (
yeart – yeart-1) to an acquisition. The categories reflect an increasing level of desperation. Category I (strongest position) represents firms that have an
increasing
Score value and an increasing sales-weighted exclusivity horizon. Category II
represents firms that have increasing
Score values, but a declining sales-weighted exclusivity
horizon. In contrast, a Category III firm is generating increasing sales, but has a declining
Score
value. Finally, Category IV (weakest position) represents firms that have both decreasing
Score
values and a decreasing sales-weighted exclusivity horizon. We place Category II firms ahead of
those in Category III since they have greater potential for generating future products and as a
result future sales. For example, a firm in the second category is one that is experiencing a
decline in sales prior to an acquisition, but it is also experiencing an increase in
Score value. The
prospect exists for the firm to be able to replace declining sales products with new ones in the
future. In contrast, a category three firm is generating increasing sales but their
Score value is
declining. This would be indicative of firm whose product pipeline is deteriorating. Thus, this
firm would have a lower prospect for being able to replace current products with new ones in the
near future. Firms were assigned to corresponding desperation index categories prior to and
subsequent to each acquisition. As we will discuss below in Table 8, 60 percent of firms were
categorized as either Category III or IV in the period prior to the acquisition. This is in contrast
to the post-acquisition period, where only 32 percent of firms were categorized as Category III or
IV. Approximately 28 percent of the acquiring firms in our sample were able to remove
themselves completely from these lower classifications. Whereas 59 percent of acquiring firms
were able to improve their categorical classification by at least one level while only 12 percent of
these firms remained at their pre-acquisition desperation level.
In addition to our base definition, we consider other variations and combinations of the
variables in our
Desperation Index in order to test the robustness of our results. First, we parse
the
Desperation Index into its two component parts – the
Score value and sales-weighted
exclusivity horizon. This will allow us to test the
levels of these variables versus their
change.
Next, we replace the sales-weighted exclusivity horizon variable with three other alternatives.
First, we test the raw number of exclusivity years remaining in the portfolio. This is a simple
summation of exclusivity years as reported in the FDA Orange Book. Second, as we discussed
above, firms are potentially able to "game" the number of exclusive years for a product. As a
result, the first measure may well understate the actual exclusivity horizon. Assuming that a firm
will not engage in a patent infringement suit unless the marginal benefit of doing so exceeds the
marginal cost of litigation, we add 30 months of exclusivity protection to drugs that have sales
equal to or in excess of $100 million in the year they would lose exclusivity protection.29 A new
summation of the exclusivity variable is then generated based on this extension. While not a
perfect measure, it should mimic more closely the response of companies. Finally, we replace
the sales-weighted exclusivity horizon with a summation of regular patent years. Again, due to
potential gaming of patents in the FDA Orange book, we use our second patent measure
generated from NERAC and Thomson Derwent. These data attempt to identify relevant data not
identified in the FDA Orange book. As a result, there is the possibility that this variable could
possibly be overstated. As such, this measure serves as an upper-bound, while the exclusivity
horizon will serve as a lower bound.
5.0
Empirical analysis
5.1 Assessing acquirer desperation and propensity to engage in acquisitions
Pharmaceutical firms experiencing declines in either their research pipeline or patented
product portfolio can respond in several ways. We focus our analysis here on the propensity of
firms to engage in outsourcing acquisitions using probit regressions. Our sample for this
analysis includes firms contained in Recombinant Capital's alliance data set from 1994-2001 and
that have both sales and pipeline data available. This allows for a homogenous sample of firms
engaged in similar activities and facing potentially similar constraints. The dependent variable is
an indicator variable,
yit that assumes a value of one for a given firm,
i, in a specific year,
t, if that firm undertakes an acquisition in a given year, and is zero otherwise. For independent
variables we use the change in
Score, R&D intensity, the log of market capitalization, a count
variable identifying the number of alliances undertaken prior to the current year (includes all
firms, not just target firms), indicator variables corresponding to each category of our potential
29 This process was repeated for drugs with $50 million and $75 million in revenues in the final year of exclusivity.
acquirer desperation index and a time trend. As a robustness check, we include the three other
definitions and constructions of the components of the
Desperation Index discussed previously.
We also refine the variable
Count to include only alliances with the target firm. See Table 1 for
variable definitions; Table 2 summarizes the variables and Table 3 presents the variable
We present the results of our probit regressions with White-Huber heteroscedasticity-
consistent standard errors in Table 4.30 Consistent with our hypothesis, we find that firms that
are more "desperate" are
more likely to engage in acquisitions. Recall that our
Desperation
Index is comprised of two components; the change in
Score value (representing progress in the
firm's new product pipeline) and the change in the sales-weighted exclusivity horizon
(representing the state of the firm's current product portfolio). Model 1 takes just one of the
component values, the change in
Score, and uses it as an independent variable. We report a
negative and significant correlation between the change in
Score value and the probability that a
firm engaged in an acquisition. This result suggests that firms with improving product pipelines
are less likely to undertake an outsourcing acquisition. In models 2 and 3, we incorporate each
of our four classifications of the
Desperation Index. Category III and IV firms -- our most
desperate firms -- are experiencing a declining sales-weighted exclusivity horizon and declining
pipeline
Score values in the case of Category IV. Of significant interest are the coefficient
estimates on
x7 and
x8 which correspond to Categories III and IV of the
Desperation Index. In model 2, both Category III and Category IV firms were
more likely than Category I firms to
engage in an acquisition. Category III firms were 11.41 percent and Category IV firms were
16.01 percent more likely to engage in acquisitions. This result suggests that as firms fall from
Category III to IV, their probability of engaging in an acquisition increases by approximately 4.6
percent. In model 3, when the number of previous alliances indicator variable (
Count) is
removed, the coefficients and resulting probabilities remain fairly stable. Again, Category III
and IV firms were more likely than Category I firms to engage in acquisitions. Category III
firms were 11.77 percent more likely and Category IV firms were 16.38 percent more likely.
Model 4 takes two of the desperation categories and combines them into a single indicator
variable,
Desperation Index, which equals one if the firm is either a Category III or IV firm.
30 The same analyses were performed with logit regressions. Unreported results are consistent with the probit analyses reported in the paper. A Hausman test was run and rejected the hypothesis that the individual-level effects were adequately modeled using a random effects approach. As such, a fixed effects model is utilized.
Using this specification, desperate firms were 13.86 percent more likely to engage in an
acquisition than Category I and II firms. These findings support recent work by Danzon
et al
(2004). They find a positive relationship between the motivation to merge and a percentage of a
firm's drugs that are old and at risk of losing patent protection.
These results suggest that we might anticipate lower or even negative abnormal returns
for acquiring firms at higher levels of desperation. However, as we discuss in the next section,
we do not find that target firms are able to extract all of the acquiring firm gains, even when the
acquirer is particularly desperate to supplement its R&D program.
In unreported regressions we test the robustness of the above results to a change in
definition of the
Desperation Index. First, we parse the
Desperation Index into its two essential
component parts – the
Score and sales-weighted exclusivity horizon. We then use the
levels of
these variables in the year prior to the acquisition to test whether a firm was more or less likely
to engage in an acquisition. In a series of regressions, using the same independent variables as
Table 4, we consistently find a negative and significant relationship between our
Score and
Acquisition variables. These findings suggest that firms with large
Score values – or relatively
healthy research pipelines – are less likely to engage in an acquisition. Likewise, firms with low
Score values – or relatively unhealthy research pipelines – were more likely to engage in an
acquisition in the following calendar year. The sales-weighted exclusivity horizon variable did
not produce the same result. The variable was consistently not significant across the additional
specifications. This finding may suggest that the decision to engage in a research type
acquisition is mainly driven by what is happening with a firm's research pipeline and not their
sales or revenues. This is consistent with the findings of Danzon
et al (2004).
When we replace the sales-weighted exclusivity horizon with our patent horizon
generated from our combination of NERAC and Thomson Derwent data sources we find results
similar to those reported in Table 4. Category II was not significant across any specification.
Categories III and IV were both negative and significant. Marginal probabilities were slightly
larger, on average, than the results we report. Category III firms were around 13 percent more
likely to engage in an acquisition than Category I firms while Category IV firms were around 19
percent more likely. When we combine Category III and IV firms together in Model 4 the
marginal probability increases slightly to 15 percent. All results using this modified definition of
the
Desperation Index are significant at least at the 5 percent level of significance.
There are several other results of note in this analysis. Firms with greater R&D intensity
have a greater propensity to undertake R&D outsourcing acquisitions. This result is consistent
with the notion that higher levels of absorptive capacity on the part of research-focused firms are
necessary for those firms to incorporate new research into their R&D programs effectively
(Cohen and Levinthal, 1989). This view is supported by Chesbrough (2003) who stresses the
importance of maintaining internal competencies even while considering the use of outsourced
research and development. Additionally, we find that smaller firms have a greater tendency to
undertake acquisitions. This is demonstrated by the consistently negative and significant
coefficient estimates for our log of market capitalization variable in Table 4. This result is
consistent with the notion that pharmaceutical R&D programs require increasing economies of
scale (Cockburn and Henderson, 1996). In order for smaller firms to improve the productivity of
their research programs, they can engage in R&D acquisitions to increase their scale. Finally,
Andrade and Stafford (2004) find that firms with a high Tobin Q are significantly more likely to
undertake both merger and non-merger investment. In unreported regressions, we do not find,
for the current sample, any statistically significant relation between Tobin's Q and the
probability that a firm engaged in an acquisition. High Q firms may very well engage in non-
merger investment, however, that question is beyond the scope of the present study.
5.2
Assessing stock market returns
We present univariate
CARs
against various independent variables in Table 5. We focus
on five specific independent variables: the relatedness of the transaction, financing method,
alliance activity, sales experience, and research experience. As discussed above, the relatedness
of the transaction measures if both the acquirer and target operate within the same therapeutic
category. Next, we focus on whether the deal was financed with stock or cash. Mixed financing
deals were included in the overall sample, but not in this specific analysis given the inability to
attribute any potential
CAR to a specific financing method. The alliance variable is an indicator
that equals one if the acquiring firm had an alliance with the target prior to the acquisition. The
sales experience variable is an indicator that equals one if the acquiring firm has patented
product sales within the same therapeutic category as the target firm prior to the acquisition. If
an acquiring company has a patented product that meets this criterion we argue that the firm has
to have some internal capabilities with respect to products in that therapeutic category – since
they had to successfully complete clinical testing and the FDA approval process in order to begin
to sell the product. Finally, we include research experience. The research experience variable is
an indicator that equals one if the acquiring firm has products in its own pipeline within the same
therapeutic category as the target firm. We anticipate that the presence of prior alliances, sales
and research experience should generate greater
CARs for acquiring firms. We present four
separate specifications. We present univariate results in the first column for the entire sample.
In columns two through four we present results for three smaller sub-samples. We break the
sample into three types. Type I transactions are deals where a biotechnology firm or technology
was acquired. Type II transactions are those deals where non-biotechnology related research and
development firms were purchased. Type III transactions are those involving a mature product
along with research and development capabilities.
The overall average abnormal return for acquiring firms, using a three-day window, is
3.91 percent and is significant at the 1 percent level.31 Average abnormal returns to target firms
were around 16.0 percent. The returns to the target firms are consistent with previous research,
as discussed above. We find similar results across the various sub-types of acquisitions.
Average abnormal returns for these sub-types were 2.81 percent, 4.29 percent and 5.29 percent,
respectively. All are significant at the 1 or 5 percent level. We provide the distribution of the
overall average abnormal returns in Table 6. We include several controls to ensure that our
results are not being driven by outliers. Panel A of Table 6 breaks the individual abnormal
returns down into magnitude ranges. From this panel, we find that only four
CARs are below
negative 15.0 percent while sixteen
CARs are greater than positive 15 percent. Panel B contains
a plot of the
CARs against their frequency. While the sample appears to be skewed slightly to
the right of zero, no large outliers appear to exist. In addition to Table 6, we performed non-
parametric tests to determine the sensitivity to outliers.32
The extant literature finds that cash-financed transactions generate superior returns than
those financed with stock (Andrade
et at, 2001). Our findings contradict this result. While cash
transactions, on average, produce average cumulative abnormal returns of 2.38 percent, those
transactions financed with equity yielded returns of 3.87 percent. Both results are significant at
31 Abnormal returns for our robustness measure for acquiring firms was 4.38 percent and significant at the 1 percent level. Recall, this
CAR was a combination of results from a three and five day window, as discussed in Section 4.2.
32 We perform a Wilcoxon signed rank test, which considers both the sign and magnitude of each transaction's cumulative the abnormal return. We reject the null hypothesis of zero CAR with a z-value of 5.692.
least at the 5 percent level and are also significantly different from each other at the 5 percent
level. Equity payments in these acquisitions may help alleviate the moral hazard problem and
align the interests of target-firm employees with those of the acquiring firm. As there is
generally a large disparity in size between acquirer and target in terms of market capitalization,
acquiring firms need to ensure that target firm managers or scientists remain committed to the
overall success of a particular research project as they transition from being owners of the firm's
research output to employees of the acquirer.
Our next three results examine different types of pre-acquisition information-gathering
activities on the part of acquirers: prior alliances, sales experience, and research experience. We
find that the presence of each of these activities generates greater abnormal returns for the
acquirer. Acquirers that engaged in alliances with the target firm prior to the acquisition
generated average abnormal returns of 4.30 percent versus returns of 3.36 percent for those firms
that did not engage in these types of alliances. Both are significant at the 1 percent level and are
significantly different from each other at the 1 percent level. Acquiring firms that had prior sales
experience within the same therapeutic category as the acquisition experienced substantially
greater average abnormal returns than those firms that did not. Firms that had prior sales
experienced average abnormal returns of 6.99 percent while those that did not experienced
average abnormal returns of only 3.08 percent. Both are significant at the 1 percent level and are
significantly different from each other at the 5 percent level.33 Finally, acquiring firms that have
existing research experience within the same therapeutic category as the target generate greater
average abnormal returns, 5.08 percent versus 3.24 percent. This result suggests that firms are
rewarded for making acquisitions within their existing areas of expertise. Again, both are
significant at the 1 percent level and are significantly different from each other at the 1 percent
level. The presence of each of these activities allows the acquiring firm to "learn" about the true
underlying value of the target. As a result, acquiring firms are able to place a more accurate
value on the target firm and generate greater positive abnormal returns for their shareholders. It
33 A robustness check on a slight change in definition was performed. Currently, the variable includes sales of a patented product for which a firm may only be distributing the product and may have had limited or no involvement in the actual development of the product. Our alliance data set was utilized in an effort to identify only marketing deals. The relevant therapeutic category for these sales was removed from the acquiring company's list if they had no other sales experience for products that they internally or co-developed within that therapeutic category. We were unable to identify any situations for which this would be necessary. As a result, we are confident in our original measure.
is also likely that these pre-acquisition information gathering activities lead to more successful
post-acquisition integration as well.
Cockburn and Henderson (2001) in their study of drug development performance find a
strong correlation between the scope of a firm's development efforts and the success probability
of individual projects. Scope is defined by the number of therapeutic categories in which a
particular company operated. Our
pipeline experience and
sales experience variables are not
scope measures. Rather they are a measure of the complementarty between the acquiring and
target firm's research and product portfolios. As such, firms undertaking these types of
outsourcing of research and development acquisitions are choosing to deepen their existing
capabilities versus broadening their overall research scope. The results for our
relatedness
variable support this claim. We find positive average cumulative abnormal returns of 3.51
percent for acquirers that operate within the same broad therapeutic category as the target firm,
as opposed to average cumulative abnormal returns of 2.57 percent for those firms that do not.
Interestingly, in addition to the scope findings, Cockburn and Henderson (2001) also found that
past successes in a therapeutic category were also positively associated with successful outcomes
of a project. These results were robust across all of their specifications. Our
sales experience
variable is a measure of exactly this. It measures whether a firm has sales of a patented product -
- which serves an indicator that the firm as experience taking a product in that therapeutic
category through the various research phases -- within the same therapeutic category as the
research being acquired from the target firm. Their finding of a greater likelihood of
development success could also provide an alternative explanation for the magnitude of the
positive abnormal return on the
sales experience variable.
5.3
Cross-sectional analysis of abnormal returns
5.3.1
Firms that engage in one of the three pre-acquisition information-gathering activities –
alliances, prior sales of patented products and research experience within the same therapeutic
category as the target – generate positive abnormal returns for their shareholders. Additionally,
each of these significantly impacts the overall magnitude of the
CAR. We report our cross-
sectional regression estimates in Table 7. Table 7 presents results for six separate specifications
that test a series of independent variables hypothesized to have an impact on the magnitude of
the
CAR while at the same time controlling for various attributes of the firm and acquisition
deals. The dependent variable for these regressions is the acquirer three day
CAR for each
acquisition in our sample. We include three groups of independent variables in our analysis.
The first three variables include our pre-acquisition information gathering activities – prior
research and sales experience and alliance activity. Next we include our
Desperation Index
measure and a measure of R&D intensity, defined as research and development expenditures
divided by sales. We also include an indicator of whether or not the firm had engaged in any
acquisitions in the previous three years. We include two financing variables indicators for cash
and equity deals. Three other variables control for various financial characteristics of the
acquiring firm – a measure of free-cash flow, Tobin's Q, and the log value of the market
capitalization of the acquiring firm. Finally, dummies are included if the acquiring firm was
based outside of the United States and if there was a contingent contract present in the deal.
Across the first four specifications we find mixed support for the pipeline experience
variable. The coefficient, across these various specifications, ranges between 0.0184 and 0.0249
and is significant only once at the 10 percent level. Prior pipeline research – firms with products
identified in the NDA pipeline – within the same therapeutic category as target firm positively
impacts the overall magnitude of the
CAR. In this case, firms are positively rewarded for buying
"what they know."
Having prior sales experience -- our proxy for FDA approved products -- within the same
therapeutic category as the target firm also positively impacts the magnitude of the
CAR. We
find strong evidence for this result across all six model specifications. In addition, the
coefficient remains fairly stable and is significant at the 1 percent level. In addition to having the
research capabilities for a specific therapeutic category, having sales experience and as a result
having a product approved by the FDA demonstrates that the particular acquiring pharmaceutical
firm has experience in taking that specific category of product through the formal FDA approval
process. Phase III testing (human clinical trials) and the FDA approval process are very
expensive and time-consuming. Firms have a clear advantage in taking new products into this
process for which they already hold some experience. Additionally, the introduction of a new
product within an existing therapeutic category would require less time to train sales
professionals and generate a new market than would a new class of products. Again, these
results imply that acquiring firm shareholders are being rewarded for staying within areas in
which they are already experts.
Alliance experience with the target firm prior to an acquisition positively impacts the
magnitude of our
CAR values across all specifications considered. Results ranged from 0.0321
to 0.0396 and were significant at the 1 percent level. On average, there were four alliances
between the firms prior to the acquisition. Presumably this prior contact should provide learning
opportunities for the acquiring firm resulting in a more appropriate valuation being placed on the
target firm. These positive impacts are consistent with Chan et al (1997) and Porrini (2004).
Next, we look at the impact that the level of desperation has on the
CAR. We find, across
five of the six model specifications, a negative impact on the overall magnitude of the
CAR.
Results are significant at the 5 percent level. More importantly, while the presence of firm level
desperation negatively impacts the
magnitude of the
CAR, the overall
CAR for these desperate
firms remains positive. The overall average abnormal return for the entire sample is 3.91
percent. Performing a univariate analysis similar to those in Table 5, the average abnormal
return for the most desperate firms was 1.73 percent, significant at the 10 percent level. This
suggests that even the most desperate firms are still able to employ pre-acquisition information-
gathering activities in order to generate positive value for their firm's shareholders. The lower
abnormal returns for these firms may be attributable to such factors as a lower internal required
rate of return for the acquiring firm in addition to the less favorable negotiating position vis-à-vis
Of the remaining independent variables, R&D intensity, stock deal, cash deal, free-cash
flow, Tobin's Q, contingent contracts and an international indicator, none are significant at any
reasonable level across six specifications. However, acquiring firms experienced a negative
impact on their
CAR if they engaged in an acquisition within the three years prior to the current
acquisition. This result is negative and significant at the 5 percent level across all six
specifications. This finding is in contrast to Fuller et al (2002). One reason for the difference
may be that the market is penalizing companies that engage in either multiple acquisitions or a
program of acquisitions in an effort to grow their R&D business. The market may perceive this
type of firm as having a weak internal research and development program that is unable to
develop new projects independently. Since new product development is the life-blood of any
pharmaceutical firm, companies that are unable to produce potential products internally may be
at a competitive disadvantage. Another reason for the difference may be the selection of firms
analyzed. Whereas this study focuses solely on the pharmaceutical sector, the same sector only
totaled 1.3 percent of the total firms analyzed in their study.
In additional unreported regression specifications, the public status of the target firm had
no significant statistical impact on the magnitude of the cumulative abnormal return. This
finding, in contrast to the extant literature, suggests that a "private company discount" does not
exist in the current study. One of the justifications for the "private company discount" is the
difficulty in valuing a company. This lends support to our argument that acquiring firms are able
to use pre-acquisition information gathering activities to lessen the uncertainty as to the
underlying value of the target firm.
5.3.2 Sensitivity
Additional specifications were tested in order to ensure the robustness of our main
findings to changes in definitions. Repeating our procedure we parse the
Desperation Index into
its two main components – the
Score and sales-weighted exclusivity horizon. In the first series
of regressions we tested the
levels of these two variables in the year prior to the acquisition.
Score – the weighted measure of the health of a firm's research pipeline – while positive was not
significant in the additional specifications. This would seem to suggest that a firm's pipeline
status in the year prior to an acquisition has little impact on the abnormal returns generated over
the three day event window. We found previously, however, that
Score played a significant role
in the probability that firm actually engaged in an acquisition. In contrast, we found both
positive and significant results for our sales-weighted exclusivity horizon. We removed the
exclusivity weighting and tested real sales and found similar results. Finally, we removed the
sales data completely and used just a straight measure of the number of exclusivity years
remaining in a firm's portfolio. Again, we found positive and significant results. These findings
are all consistent with our findings on
Desperation Index in Table 7. The desperation level of a
firm negatively impacts the magnitude of its
CAR.
Given the potential pitfalls of using exclusivity as an adequate measure of the health of a
firms patented product portfolio we employ additional measures. First, in an attempt to control
for some of the "gaming" that may take place in order to garner additional years of exclusivity,
for example, by engaging in patent litigation, we add 30 months of exclusivity onto each product
in their last year of exclusivity if the drug had at least $100 million in revenues.34 Arguably a
company would not engage in the expense of patent litigation if the marginal benefit of doing so
was less than the marginal cost. We find across various specifications a positive and significant
(at the 5 percent level of significance) impact on the magnitude of the
CAR. Again, this finding
is consistent with our reported
Desperation Index findings in Table 7.
We next remove the exclusivity variable and replace it with our patent data variable
constructed from NERAC and Thomson Derwent in order to test robustness of our results across
differing legal protections. Our findings here are mixed. The coefficient remains positive –
consistent with the exclusivity findings – however the variable is only significant at the 10
percent level in a limited number of specifications. This finding only suggests there is
potentially a real difference between the impact a firm's patent profile and a firm's exclusivity
profile has on the magnitude of the
CAR. Since this variable serves as an upper-bound measure,
it is possible that these results are a function of the way the variable is constructed.
5.4
Cross-sectional analysis of post-acquisition success measures
In addition to the abnormal returns result discussed earlier, we find positive changes to
the acquiring firm's
Score value and product sales figures in the year following the acquisition.
The
Score value for a firm is a weighted measure of the health of a firm's research pipeline. An
increase in the
Score value of a firm after an acquisition is suggestive of improvements to the
underlying pipeline. We present the distribution of firms across the various levels of
desperation, both pre- and post-acquisition in Table 8. As presented in Panel A of Table 8, 94
firms or 59 percent of the firms in our sample improved their level of desperation through the use
of acquisitions. This means that in the year following an acquisition, acquiring firms moved
from one of the four levels of desperation, previously defined, to a less desperate level. In other
words, through the use of acquisitions, firms are able to increase either their score value or
weighted sales or both. Another 19 firms or 12 percent of firms maintained their level of
34 This process was repeated for drugs with $50 million and $75 million in revenues in the final year of exclusivity.
desperation. In total, 71 percent of firms either improved or maintained their level of
Panel B presents the average change in sales and score values for the distribution of
desperation categories
post-acquisition. This panel suggests that firms that were able to improve
their level of desperation in categories I (least desperate) or II were most successful in adding to
their underlying research score value. As discussed in Panel A, 67.50 percent of firms fell into
one of these two categories post-acquisition. The average change in
Score value for a category
I firm (least desperate) post acquisition is positive, while the average change in
Score value for a
category IV firm (most desperate) is negative. Moreover, the average change in sales for
category I firms was positive, while the average change in sales for category IV firms was
negative. The post-acquisition change in product sales needs to be viewed very cautiously. As
most research is acquired while still in phase testing, the sales impact will not be felt until some
time in the future. The more important result, we feel, is the post-acquisition change in the
Score
value since this is a direct measure of the health of a firm's research portfolio.
Pisano (1991) suggests that that acquisition of biotechnology firms can be a "dangerous
strategy" particularly when acquisitions are used to overcome a weakness in internal capabilities.
As we discuss next, we find consistent with Chesbrough (2003) that this is not always the case.
Table 9 presents cross-sectional regression results for these post-acquisition measures. The
change in
Score value (scoret+1 – scoret) and change in product sales (salest+1 – salest), respectively, are used as dependent variables. For both regression models we present five
separate specifications. As before, we include and test a variety of independent variables that we
feel have an impact on the two dependent variables. We find in the first regression model (
∆
Score post-acquisition is the dependent variable) that the coefficient on the variable
Desperation
Index is positive and significant at least at the 5 percent level. This result suggests that desperate
firms are experiencing positive post-acquisition changes to their
Score value through the use of
acquisitions. As the
Score value is a measure of pipeline health, these improvements justify the
use of acquisition activity as a tool to help improve the research portfolio of the firm. For the
next regression model (
∆ Sales post-acquisition is the dependent variable) focuses on the post-
acquisition changes in product sales. Again, these results need to be viewed with caution since
many of the acquisitions contained products still in various stages of phase testing. As a result,
the financial impacts of their presence may not be realized until some period in the future, likely
greater than one year after an acquisition. Some acquiring firms, however, did purchase either
mature products along with research capabilities or products in late-stage or FDA approval
process. Again, the coefficient on the variable
Desperation Index is positive and significant.
Desperate firms that included these types of products in their acquisition were able to positively
impact their post-acquisition change in product sales. Interestingly, firms that acquired a sales
force as part of the acquisition showed positive changes to their post-acquisition change in sales.
This result implies that target firms that had a sales force present also had products generating
some type of revenues. As such, it is not surprising that the acquiring firm experienced a
positive change in post-acquisition sales.
6.0 Conclusion
The pharmaceutical industry is characterized by large amounts of research and
development. It is also an industry dependent upon that research to be productive and generate
revenues in order to finance future research. As such, the protection and health of a firm's
research pipeline is of paramount importance. Managers are faced with several options on how
to go about replenishing that research pipeline. In this paper, we have sought to understand how
pharmaceutical companies have employed acquisitions in an effort to combat deteriorating
research pipelines and declining patented product portfolios. For acquisitions characterized by
information asymmetries, we find evidence consistent with the proposition that acquirers are able
to avoid the winner's curse. Specifically, we find a positive and significant correlation between
acquirer returns and pre-acquisition information-gathering activities. We also find, on average,
that companies experiencing a deterioration of their research pipeline and product sales were
more likely to engage in an acquisition. Moreover, these firms were either able to stabilize or to
reverse the pipeline declines that they were experiencing.
We believe considerable opportunities exist for further empirical research into these
issues. It would be of interest to see if these results generalize across other high-tech industries;
for example, the software industry. In this project, we employed a broad view of firm level
research activities being undertaken by pharmaceutical firms. Extensions of the current analysis
such as tracking research further into the future post-acquisition should yield additional
important insights. Finally, exploring more fully how firms employ alliances to complement
internal research programs should be a rewarding area for future research.
References
Ackerlof, G., 1970. The market for "lemons" quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 84, 488-500.
Anand, J., Singh, J., 1997. Asset re-deployment, acquisitions and corporate strategies in declining industries.
Strategic Management Journal 18, 99-118.
Andrade, G., Mitchell, M., Stafford, E., 2001. New evidence and perspectives on mergers. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 15, 103-120.
Asquith, P., Bruner R., Mullins, D., 1983. The gains to bidding firms from merger. Journal of Financial Economics
Baker, J., Bresnehan, T., 1985. The gains from merger and collusion in product-differentiated industries. Journal of
Industrial Economics 33, 427-433.
Ball, S., Bazerman, M., Carroll, J., 1991. An evaluation of learning in a bilateral winner's curse. Organizational
Behavior and Human Decision Processes 48, 1-22.
Barton, D.M., Sherman, R., 1984. The price and profit effects of horizontal merger: a case study. Journal of
Industrial Economics 33, 165-177.
Berger, P.G., Ofek, E., 1995. Diversification's effects on firm value. Journal of Financial Economics 37, 39-65. Bradley, M., Desai A., Kim, E.H., 1988. Synergistic gains from corporate acquisitions and their divisions between
the stockholders of target and acquiring firms. Journal of Financial Economics 21, 3-40.
Brown, S., Warner, J., 1980. Measuring security price performance. Journal of Financial Economics 8, 205-258. _, 1985. Using daily stock returns: the case of event studies. Journal of Financial Economics 14, 3-31. Bruner, R., 2002. Does M&A pay? A survey of evidence for the decision-maker. Journal of Applied Finance 12, 48-
Bulow, J., 2003. The gaming of pharmaceutical patents. Unpublished Stanford Business School working paper. Campbell, J., Lo, A., MacKinley, C., 1997. The econometrics of financial markets. Princeton University Press,
Capron, L., 1999. The long term performance of horizontal acquisitions. Strategic Management Journal 20, 987-
Chan, S., Kensinger, J., Keown, A., Martin, J., 1997. Do strategic alliances create value? Journal of Financial
Economics 46, 199-221.
Chesbrough, H.W., 2003. Open innovation: The new imperative for creating and profiting from technology. Boston,
Harvard Business School Press.
Cockburn, I., Henderson, R., 1996. Scale, scope, and spillovers: The determinants of research productivity in drug
discovery. The Rand Journal of Economics 27, 32-60.
_, 2003. Scale and scope in drug development: unpacking the advantages of size in pharmaceutical research.
Journal of Health Economics 20, 1033-1057.
Coff, R.W., 1999. How buyers cope with uncertainty when acquiring firms in knowledge-intensive industries:
caveat emptor. Organization Science 10, 144-161.
Cohen, W.M., Levinthal, D.A., 1989. Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&D. The Economic Journal 99,
Comment, R., Schwert, G.W., 1995. Poison or placebo? evidence on the deterrence and wealth effects of modern
antitakeover measures. Journal of Financial Economics 39, 3-43.
Congressional Budget Office, 1998. How increased competition from generic drugs has affected prices and returns
in the pharmaceutical industry. Washington, D.C., July.
Danzon, P., Epstein, A., Nicholson, S., 2004. Mergers and acquisitions in the pharmaceutical and biotech industries.
NBER Working Paper Series, Paper 10536.
DiMasi, J.A. 2001. New drug development in U.S. 1963-1999. Clinical Pharmacology & Therapeutics 69. _. 1991. Cost of innovation in the pharmaceutical industry. Journal of Health Economics 10, 107-142. Deeds, D.L., Hill, C.W.L., 1996. Strategic alliances and the rate of new product development: an empirical study of
entrepreneurial biotechnology firms. Journal of Business Venturing 11, 41-55.
Dodd, P., Warner, J., 1983. On corporate governance: a study of proxy contests. Journal of Financial Economics 11,
Eckbo, E., 1983. Horizontal mergers, collusion, and stockholder wealth. Journal of Financial Economics 11, 241-
Eckbo, E., Thorburn, K., 2000. Gains to bidder firms revisited: domestic and foreign acquisitions in Canada.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 35, 1-25.
Federal Trade Commission, 2002. Generic entry prior to patent expiration: An FTC study. Washington, D.C., July. Hayward, M., 2002. When do firms learn from their acquisition experience? Evidence from 1990-1995. Strategic
Management Journal 23, 21-39.
Healey, P., Palepu, K., Ruback, R., 1992. Does corporate performance improve after mergers? Journal of Financial
Economics 31, 135-175.
Holmstrom, B., Kaplan, S.M., 2001. Corporate governance and merger activity in the United States: making sense
of the 1980s and 1990s. Journal of Economic Perspectives 15, 121-144.
Houston, J., James, C., Ryngaert, M., 2001. Where do merger gains come from? Bank mergers from the perspective
of insiders and outsiders. Journal of Financial Economics 60, 285-331.
James, A.D., 2002. The strategic management of mergers and acquisitions in the pharmaceutical industry:
developing a resource based perspective. Technology Analysis & Strategic Management 14(3), 299-313.
Jarrell, G., Brickley, J., Netter, J., 1988. The market for corporate control: empirical evidence since 1980. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 2, 49-68.
Jensen, M., Ruback, R., 1983. The market for corporate control. Journal of Financial Economics 11, 5-50. Jensen, R., Thursby, M., 2001. Proofs and prototypes for sale: the licensing of university inventions. American Economic Review 91, 240-259.
Kohler, H., 1985. Statistics for business and economics. Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman. Kohlers, N., Kohlers, T., 2000. The value creation potential of high-tech mergers. Financial Analysts Journal, 40-48. Koeplin, J., Sarin, A., Shapiro, A., 2000. The private company discount. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 12,
Krieger, D., Ruback, R.S., 2001. Merck & company: evaluating a drug licensing opportunity. Harvard Business
School Case #9-201-023.
Lang, L., Stultz, R., Walkling, R., 1989. Managerial performance, tobin's q, and the gains from successful tender
offers. Journal of Financial Economics 24, 137-154.
Lerner, J., Shane, H., Tsai, A., 2003. Do equity financing cycles matter? Evidence from biotechnology alliances.
Journal of Financial Economics 67, 411-446.
Lyroudi, K., Lazaridis, J., Subeniotis, D., 1999. Impact of international mergers and acquisitions on shareholder's
wealth: a european perspective. Journal of Financial Management and Analysis 12, 1-14.
McWilliams, A., Siegel, D., 1997. Event studies in management research: theoretical and empirical issues. Academy
of Management Journal 40, 626-657.
Milgrom, P., 1989. Auctions and bidding: a primer. Journal of Economic Perspectives 3, 3-22. Mitchell, M., Lehn, K., 1990. Do bad bidders become good targets? Journal of Political Economy 98, 372-398. Mulherin, H., Boone, A.L., 2000. Comparing acquisitions and divestitures. Journal of Corporate Finance 6, 117-139. Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America, 2002.
Industry Profile 2002, http://www.pharma.org. Porrini, P., 2004. Can a previous alliance between an acquirer and a target affect acquisition performance? Journal
of Management 30(4) 545-562.
Ravenscraft, D., Long, W., 2000. Paths to creating value in pharmaceutical mergers. In
Mergers and Productivity,
NBER Conference Report series. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, 287-323.
Ravenscraft, D., Scherer, F., 1989. The profitability of mergers. International Journal of Industrial Organization 7,
Rau, P.R., Rodgers, K.J., 2002. Do bidders hire top-tier investment banks to certify value? Working Paper, Krannert
School of Management, Purdue University.
Rau, R.P., Vermaelen, T., 1998. Glamour, value and the post-acquisition performance of acquiring firms. Journal of
Financial Economics 49, 223-253.
Ritter, J., 1991. The long-run performance of initial public offerings. Journal of Finance 42, 365-94. Roll, R., 1986. The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers. Journal of Business 59, 197-216. Rothaermel, F., 2001. Complementary assets, strategic alliances, and the incumbent's advantage: An empirical study
of industry and firm effects in the biopharmaceutical industry. Research Policy 30, 1235-1251.
Samuelson, W., Bazerman, M., 1985. Negotiation under the winner's curse. In V. Smith (Ed.), Research in
Experimental Economics (Vol. III). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Schipper, K., Thompson, R., 1983. Evidence on the capitalized value of merger activity for acquiring firms. Journal
of Financial Economics
11, 437-467.
Schwert, G., 1996. Markup pricing in mergers and acquisitions. Journal of Financial Economics 41, 153-162. Shan, W., Walker, G., Kogut, B., 1994. Interfirm cooperation and startup innovation in the biotechnology industry.
Strategic Management Journal 15, 387-394.
White, H., 1980. A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity.
Econometrica 48, 817-838.
Definition and description of regression-model independent variables. Different dependent variables are utilized - cumulative abnormal returns (CARj) are used in
Table 7 and ∆ Score and ∆ Sales are used in additional cross section
analyses presented in
Table 9. Variable
Definition/Description
Weighted value (non-monetary) of company research pipeline
∆ score pre-acquisition
Pre-acquisition change in weighted value of research pipeline (scoret – scoret-1)
∆ score post-acquisition
Post acquisition change in pipeline weighted value (scoret+1 – scoret)
Log Sales Level
Log value of real life-cycle-weighted pharmaceutical sales
∆ sales pre-acquisition
Pre-acquisition change in weighted sales (log sales levelt – log sales levelt-1)
∆ sales post-acquisition
Post acquisition change in weighted sales (log sales levelt+1 – log sales levelt)
R&D expenses/sales (real 1999 dollars)
Pipeline Experience
Dummy = 1 if acquiring company has NDA pipeline research in the
same therapeutic category as the target firm
Sales Experience
Dummy = 1 if acquiring company has patented pharmaceutical product
sales in the same therapeutic category as the target firm
Dummy = 1 if acquiring company has alliance with target firm
prior to
Dummy = 1 if acquiring company was paying a royalty to the target
Early Stage Alliance
Dummy = 1 if acquiring company has early stage product alliance with
Desperation Index (pre-acquisition)
Dummy = 1 if acquiring company was assigned to desperation
∆ Desperation Index post-acquisition
Dummy = 1 if acquiring company improved level of desperation post acquisition
Prior Acquisition
Dummy = 1 if acquiring company has prior acquisition experience in
the three years prior to the latest acquisition
Dummy = 1 if acquisition was stock financed
Dummy = 1 if acquisition was cash financed
Contingent Contract
Dummy = 1 if contingent contract was present
Dummy = 1 if acquiring and target firms operate within the same
Dummy = 1 if sales force personnel were part of acquisition
Log of market capitalization
Dummy = 1 if acquiring firm was an international firm
Descriptive statistics for firms making 160 research and development related acquisitions in the 1994-2001 period; these variables are used in (1) probit results analyzing the characteristics that impact the probability a firm engages in an acquisition,
Table 4;
(2) analysis of the event study results,
Table 5; (3) cross-section results utilizing the cumulative abnormal return as the dependent variable,
Table 7; and, (4) cross-section results utilizing two separate measures of success as the dependent variable,
Table 9.
Score (in year of acquisition)
post-acquisition
Correlation matrix for relevant variables utilized in the following analyses: (1) probit estimation (
Table 4); (2) cumulative abnormal return cross-sectional regressions (
Table 7); and, (3) post-acquisition cross-sectional regressions (
Table 9). The numbers listed horizontally across the top row correspond to the numbers and variables listed vertically on the table. See
Table 1 for variable definitions.
Pipeline Experience
Sales Experience
Early Stage Alliance
Desperation Index
-0.0494 -0.0641 -0.0010 -0.0580 -0.0109 -0.0512
Prior Acquisition
11. Free Cash Flow
-0.0077 -0.0661 -0.0663 -0.0511 -0.0575
0.0103 -0.1106 -0.0490
13. Log Market Cap
0.1865 -0.1283 -0.0139 -0.0616
-0.1558 -0.1099 -0.2093
15. International
-0.0024 -0.0058
Probit estimates for our data regress an acquisition indicator (= 1 if an acquisition took place) on a series of independent variables expected to impact a firm's probability of engaging in an acquisition. The period for this analysis runs from 1994-2001. The universe of firms for this analysis includes all firms contained in the Recombinant Capital alliance data set that have pipeline and patented product information available.
Count is defined as the total number of alliances that the acquiring firm is engaged in on a year-by-year basis. Desperation Index categories III and IV are the most severe levels of firm desperation. The variable
Desperation Index is an aggregated indicator variable that assumes a value of one if the acquirer is in Categories III or IV and is zero otherwise. Φ is the standard cumulative normal distribution. See
Table 1 for all other variable definitions. Firm
and time effects were included. We use White's (1980) heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors to compute the appropriate test statistics included in parentheses below the coefficient estimates. We test the following model:
P(yi,t≠0 xi,t) = Φ(x1i,t + x2i,t + x3i,t + x4i,t + x5i,t + x6i,t + x7i,t + x8i,t + x9i,t + FE + c)
∂Φ/∂xi = φ(
xb)bi
Dependent variable:
Acquisition Indicator Independent Variable Model
1 ∂Φ/∂x Model
2 ∂Φ/∂x Model
3 ∂Φ/∂x Model
x1: Change Score (Pre-Acquisition)
x2: R&D Intensity
-0.0965 -0.0214 -0.0881 -0.0196 -0.0894 -0.0201
x5: Desperation Index – Category I
x6: Desperation Index – Category II
x7: Desperation Index – Category III
x8: Desperation Index – Category IV
(2.96)*** c : Constant
significant at the 1% level
significant at the 5% level
significant at the 10% level
Event study estimates evaluating the cumulative abnormal return versus the presence of various independent variables. Type I transactions involve the acquisition of biotechnology R&D; Type II transactions involve the acquisition of general R&D; and, Type III transactions involve the acquisition of a mature product along with R&D.
t-statistics are reported in parentheses. The second column reports the
t-statistic that tests whether each of the sub-categories (for the overall sample) are statistically different from each other (difference of the means). See
Table 1 for definitions of variables. *** significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5% level; * significant at the 10% level. Overall
t-test
Financing 2.19**
Alliances 2.58***
Prior Alliances
No Prior Alliances
Sales Experience
Research Experience
Prior Experience
No Prior Experience 3.24 percent
The dispersion of cumulative abnormal returns
(CARs) are presented. Following Dodd & Warner (1983),
standardized abnormal returns
(SARs) are computed by dividing the abnormal return (AR) by its standard deviation.
These standardized abnormal returns
(SARs) are then aggregated over the number of the days in the event window,
k to generate a cumulative abnormal return
(CAR). Panel A provides a simple count of the number of
CARs. Panel A
provides for a simple count of the number of
CARs that are located in various intervals. Panel B presents the same
information in a bar graph with a standard normal distribution overlapping the presented data.
Number of observed
abnormal returns
CAR ≤ −15.0% 4
−15.0% <
CAR < −10.0%
−10.0% ≤
CAR < 5
− 5.0% ≤
CAR < 0.0%
0.0% ≤
CAR < 5.0%
5.0% ≤
CAR < 10.0%
10.0% ≤
CAR < 15.0%
15.0% ≤
CAR
Cumulative abnormal returns
Cross-sectional regression estimates and independent variables from regressing the cumulative abnormal return (CAR) on selected independent variables for 160 announcements of acquisitions relating to the outsourcing of research and development. CARs are from the three day event window. The period for this analysis runs from 1994-2001. Year fixed effects are included in all specifications. White's (1980) heteroskedasticity-consistent
t-statistics are reported in parentheses. See
Table 1 for variable definitions. Dependent variable: Acquirer
CAR Independent Variables Model
Pipeline Experience
Sales Experience
(3.01)*** (2.89)*** (3.12)*** (2.93)*** (3.12)*** (2.65)***
(3.21)*** (3.28)*** (3.11)*** (3.59)*** (2.99)*** (2.67)***
-0.0442 -0.0428 -0.0436 -0.0406 -0.0362
(2.41)** (2.34)** (2.42)** (2.24)** (2.26)**
-0.0211 -0.0204 -0.0185 -0.0204 -0.0174 -0.0219
(2.34)** (2.31)** (2.17)** (2.31)** (2.12)** (2.41)**
-0.0024 -0.0031 -0.0035 -0.0028 -0.0041 -0.0057
(0.45) (0.62) (0.98) (0.56) (1.22) (1.73)*
155 155 160 155 160 155
0.26 0.25 0.22 0.24 0.22 0.22
2.78 2.64 2.91 2.87 3.12 2.58
significant at the 1% level
significant at the 5% level
significant at the 10% level
Panel A: Distribution of acquiring firms across desperation categories
Changes in desperation index prior to and post acquisition. Classifications are as follows: Class 1 indicates firms with increasing or constant score values and increasing weighted-sales; class 2 indicates firms with increasing or constant score values and decreasing weighted-sales; class 3 indicates firms with decreasing score values and increasing or constant weighted-sales; and, class 4 indicates firms with decreasing score values and decreasing weighted-sales. Class 1 firms are "less desperate" than those firms in class 4. Improvement in level of desperation Number
Improved level of desperation
Level of desperation remained constant
Worsened level of desperation
Pre-Acquisition Distribution of
Post-Acquisition Distribution of
Firms Across Desperation Categories
Firms Across Desperation Categories
Category Frequency Percent
Category Frequency Percent
(least desperate)
(least desperate)
(most desperate)
(most desperate)
Panel B: Distribution of acquiring firms across various post-acquisition measures
Changes in sales and NDA pipeline score values in the calendar year following the acquisition. The NDA score value is a proxy for the overall health of a firm's research pipeline. An increase in score value would signal that the firm's pipeline has strengthened. ∆ Score is defined as scoret+1 – scoret,. ∆ Sales is defined as salest+1 – salest. Classifications are as follows: Class 1 indicates firms with increasing or constant score
values and increasing weighted-sales; class 2 indicates firms with increasing or constant score values and decreasing weighted-sales; class 3 indicates firms with decreasing score values and increasing or constant weighted-sales; and, class 4 indicates firms with decreasing score values and decreasing weighted-sales. Weighted sales values are log values of 1999 constant dollars.
-173.10 228.06 -1059.6 -3
-71.34 66.07 -273.6 -3
1.0966 2.4109 0.2436 10.82
-0.2784 1.4465 -9.7067 -0.0067
0.4872 1.5877 0
-0.8373 3.2896 -14.345 -1.5194
Cross-sectional regression estimates and independent variables from two separate regressions are reported. First, ∆ Score, defined as scoret+1 – scoret, is regressed on a series of independent variables thought to have an impact on the firm's underlying research portfolio. Second, ∆ Sales, defined as salest+1 – salest, is regressed on a series of independent variables thought to have an impact on the firm's underlying weighted-sales.
The period for this analysis runs from 1994-2001. White's (1980) heteroskedasticity-consistent
t-statistics are reported in parentheses. See
Table 1 for variable definitions. *** 1% level of significance; ** 5% level of significance; and, * 10% level of significance. Dependent Variable
post-acquisition
-0.0357 -0.1566 -0.1910 -0.2131 -0.0041
Desperation Index
0.12 0.08 0.06 0.05 0.09
∆ Sales post-acquisition
Pipeline Experience
Desperation Index
0.15 0.15 0.15 0.11 0.10
Table 1: Sum of Exlcusivity Exclusivity Protection
Table 2: Industry Pipeline Breakdown 1993-2001
Source: http://tiger.gatech.edu/files/gt_tiger_outsourcing.pdf
des établissements de santé Cet ouvrage a été rédigé par le Conseil Médical de Sham dans le but d'appor- ter un point de vue, celui d'un assureur spécialisé, sur la gestion des risques dans le domaine de la prise en charge médicamenteuse. Sécurisation de la prise en charge Il se veut synthétique et argumenté, pour permettre à l'ensemble des person-
Journal of Experimental Marine Biology and Ecology 352 (2007) 226 – 233 Individual relationship between aneuploidy of gill cells and growth rate in the cupped oysters Crassostrea angulata, C. gigas and their reciprocal hybrids Frederico M. Batista a,b,1, Alexandra Leitão a,c,1, Vera G. Fonseca d,e, Radhouan Ben-Hamadou e, Francisco Ruano f, Maria A. Henriques b, Henrique Guedes-Pinto c, Pierre Boudry d,⁎